Powered by
TTSReader
Share this page on
Article provided by Wikipedia


Main articles: "Garnaut Climate Change Review, "Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme, and "Clean Energy Bill 2011

In 2003 the New South Wales (NSW) state government unilaterally established the NSW Greenhouse Gas Abatement Scheme[88] to reduce emissions by requiring electricity generators and large consumers to purchase NSW Greenhouse Abatement Certificates (NGACs). This has prompted the rollout of free energy-efficient compact fluorescent lightbulbs and other energy-efficiency measures, funded by the credits. This scheme has been criticised by the Centre for Energy and Environmental Markets (CEEM) of the "UNSW because of its lack of effectiveness in reducing emissions, its lack of transparency and its lack of verification of the additionality of emission reductions.[89]

Both the incumbent "Howard "Coalition government and the "Rudd "Labor opposition promised to implement an emissions trading scheme (ETS) before the "2007 federal election. Labor won the election, with the new government proceeding to implement an ETS. The government introduced the "Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme, which the "Liberals supported with "Malcolm Turnbull as leader. "Tony Abbott questioned an ETS, saying the best way to reduce emissions is with a "simple tax".[90] Shortly before the carbon vote, Abbott defeated Turnbull in a leadership challenge, and from there on the Liberals opposed the ETS. This left the government unable to secure passage of the bill and it was subsequently withdrawn.

"Julia Gillard defeated Rudd in a leadership challenge and promised not to introduce a carbon tax, but would look to legislate a price on carbon [91] when taking the government to the "2010 election. In the first "hung parliament result in 70 years, the government required the support of crossbenchers including the "Greens. One requirement for Greens support was a carbon price, which Gillard proceeded with in forming a minority government. A fixed carbon price would proceed to a floating-price ETS within a few years under the plan. The fixed price lent itself to characterisation as a carbon tax and when the government proposed the "Clean Energy Bill in February 2011,[92] the opposition claimed it to be a broken election promise.[93]

The bill was passed by the "Lower House in October 2011[94] and the "Upper House in November 2011.[95] The Liberal Party vowed to overturn the bill if elected.[96] The bill thus resulted in passage of the Clean Energy Act, which possessed a great deal of flexibility in its design and uncertainty over its future.

The "Liberal/National coalition government elected in September 2013 has promised to reverse the climate legislation of the previous government.[97] In July 2014, the carbon tax was repealed as well as the Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) that was to start in 2015.[98]

New Zealand[edit]

New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme and "Climate change in New Zealand
""
""
New Zealand Unit Prices 2010 to 2015

The New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme (NZ ETS) is a partial-coverage all-free allocation uncapped highly internationally linked emissions trading scheme. The NZ ETS was first legislated in the "Climate Change Response (Emissions Trading) Amendment Act 2008 in September 2008 under the "Fifth Labour Government of New Zealand[99][100] and then amended in November 2009[101] and in November 2012[102] by the "Fifth National Government of New Zealand.

The NZ ETS covers forestry (a net sink), energy (43.4% of total 2010 emissions), industry (6.7% of total 2010 emissions) and waste (2.8% of total 2010 emissions) but not pastoral agriculture (47% of 2010 total emissions).[103] Participants in the NZ ETS must surrender two emissions units (either an international 'Kyoto' unit or a New Zealand-issued unit) for every three tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent emissions reported or they may choose to buy NZ units from the government at a fixed price of NZ$25.[104]

Individual sectors of the economy have different entry dates when their obligations to report emissions and surrender emission units take effect. Forestry, which contributed net removals of 17.5 "Mts of "CO2e in 2010 (19% of NZ's 2008 emissions,[105]) entered the NZ ETS on 1 January 2008.[106] The stationary energy, industrial processes and liquid fossil fuel sectors entered the NZ ETS on 1 July 2010. The waste sector (landfill operators) entered on 1 January 2013.[107] Methane and nitrous oxide emissions from pastoral agriculture are not included in the NZ ETS. (From November 2009, agriculture was to enter the NZ ETS on 1 January 2015[104])

The NZ ETS is highly linked to international carbon markets as it allows the importing of most of the "Kyoto Protocol emission units. However, as of June 2015, the scheme will effectively transition into a domestic scheme, with restricted access to international Kyoto units (CERs, ERUs and RMUs).[108] The NZ ETS has a domestic unit; the 'New Zealand Unit' (NZU), which is issued by free allocation to emitters, with no auctions intended in the short term.[109] Free allocation of NZUs varies between sectors. The commercial fishery sector (who are not participants) have a free allocation of units on a historic basis.[104] Owners of pre-1990 forests have received a fixed free allocation of units.[106] Free allocation to emissions-intensive industry,[110][111] is provided on an output-intensity basis. For this sector, there is no set limit on the number of units that may be allocated.[112] The number of units allocated to eligible emitters is based on the average emissions per unit of output within a defined 'activity'.[113] Bertram and Terry (2010, p 16) state that as the NZ ETS does not 'cap' emissions, the NZ ETS is not a cap and trade scheme as understood in the economics literature.[114]

Some stakeholders have criticized the New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme for its generous free allocations of emission units and the lack of a carbon price signal (the "Parliamentary Commissioner for the Environment),[115] and for being ineffective in reducing emissions ("Greenpeace Aotearoa New Zealand).[116]

The NZ ETS was reviewed in late 2011 by an independent panel, which reported to the Government and public in September 2011.[117]

European Union[edit]

European Union Emission Trading Scheme

The European Union Emission Trading Scheme (or EU ETS) is the largest multi-national, greenhouse gas emissions trading scheme in the world. It is one of the EU's central policy instruments to meet their cap set in the Kyoto Protocol (Jones et al.., 2007, p. 64).[118]

After voluntary "trials in the UK and Denmark, Phase I began operation in January 2005 with all 15 member states of the "European Union participating.[119] The program caps the amount of carbon dioxide that can be emitted from large installations with a net heat supply in excess of 20 MW, such as power plants and carbon intensive factories[120] and covers almost half (46%) of the EU's Carbon Dioxide emissions.[121] Phase I permits participants to trade among themselves and in validated credits from the developing world through Kyoto's "Clean Development Mechanism. Credits are gained by investing in clean technologies and low-carbon solutions, and by certain types of emission-saving projects around the world to cover a proportion of their emissions.[122]

During Phases I and II, allowances for emissions have typically been given free to firms, which has resulted in them getting windfall profits (CCC, 2008, p. 149).[123] Ellerman and Buchner (2008) (referenced by Grubb et al.., 2009, p. 11) suggested that during its first two years in operation, the "EU ETS turned an expected increase in emissions of 1%-2% per year into a small absolute decline.[124] Grubb et al.. (2009, p. 11) suggested that a reasonable estimate for the emissions cut achieved during its first two years of operation was 50-100 MtCO2 per year, or 2.5%-5%.

A number of design flaws have limited the effectiveness of scheme (Jones et al.., 2007, p. 64). In the initial 2005-07 period, emission caps were not tight enough to drive a significant reduction in emissions (CCC, 2008, p. 149). The total allocation of allowances turned out to exceed actual emissions. This drove the carbon price down to zero in 2007. This oversupply was caused because the allocation of allowances by the EU was based on emissions data from the European Environmental Agency in Copenhagen, which uses a horizontal activity-based emissions definition similar to the United Nations, the EU ETS Transaction log in Brussels, but a vertical installation-based emissions measurement system. This caused an oversupply of 200 million tonnes (10% of market) in the EU ETS in the first phase and collapsing prices.[125]

Phase II saw some tightening, but the use of JI and CDM offsets was allowed, with the result that no reductions in the EU will be required to meet the Phase II cap (CCC, 2008, pp. 145, 149). For Phase II, the cap is expected to result in an emissions reduction in 2010 of about 2.4% compared to expected emissions without the cap (business-as-usual emissions) (Jones et al.., 2007, p. 64). For Phase III (2013–20), the "European Commission proposed a number of changes, including:

In January 2008, Norway, Iceland, and Liechtenstein joined the European Union Emissions Trading System ("EU ETS), according to a publication from the "European Commission.[126] The "Norwegian Ministry of the Environment has also released its draft National Allocation Plan which provides a carbon cap-and-trade of 15 million metric tonnes of CO2, 8 million of which are set to be auctioned.[127]["citation needed] According to the OECD Economic Survey of Norway 2010, the nation "has announced a target for 2008-12 10% below its commitment under the Kyoto Protocol and a 30% cut compared with 1990 by 2020."[128] In 2012, EU-15 emissions was 15.1% below their base year level. Based on figures for 2012 by the European Environment Agency, EU-15 emissions averaged 11.8% below base-year levels during the 2008-2012 period. This means the EU-15 over-achieved its first Kyoto target by a wide margin.[129]

Tokyo, Japan[edit]

Tokyo Metropolitan Government

The Japanese city of Tokyo is like a country in its own right in terms of its energy consumption and GDP. Tokyo consumes as much energy as "entire countries in Northern Europe, and its production matches the GNP of the world's 16th largest country".[130] A scheme to limit carbon emissions launched in April 2010 covers the top 1,400 emitters in Tokyo, and is enforced and overseen by the Tokyo Metropolitan Government.[131][132] Phase 1, which is similar to Japan's scheme, ran until 2015. (Japan had an ineffective voluntary emissions reductions system for years,[133] but no nationwide cap-and-trade program.) Emitters must cut their emissions by 6% or 8% depending on the type of organization; from 2011, those who exceed their limits must buy matching allowances or invest in renewable-energy certificates or offset credits issued by smaller businesses or branch offices.[134] Polluters that fail to comply will be fined up to 500,000 yen plus credits for 1.3 times excess emissions.[135] In its fourth year, emissions were reduced by 23% compared to base-year emissions.[136] In phase 2, (FY2015-FY2019), the target is expected to increase to 15%-17%. The aim is to cut Tokyo's carbon emissions by 25% from 2000 levels by 2020.[134] These emission limits can be met by using technologies such as solar panels and advanced fuel-saving devices.[132]

United States[edit]

Climate change in the United States and "Acid Rain Program

An early example of an emission trading system has been the SO2 trading system under the framework of the "Acid Rain Program of the 1990 "Clean Air Act in the U.S. Under the program, which is essentially a cap-and-trade emissions trading system, SO2 emissions were reduced by 50% from 1980 levels by 2007.[137] Some experts argue that the cap-and-trade system of SO2 emissions reduction has reduced the cost of controlling acid rain by as much as 80% versus source-by-source reduction.[21][138] The SO2 program was challenged in 2004, which set in motion a series of events that led to the 2011 "Cross-State Air Pollution Rule (CSAPR). Under the CSAPR, the national SO2 trading program was replaced by four separate trading groups for SO2 and NOx.[139] California’s cap-and-trade program ranks only second to the ETS (European Trading System) carbon market in the world.[140]

In 1997, the State of "Illinois adopted a trading program for "volatile organic compounds in most of the Chicago area, called the Emissions Reduction Market System.[141] Beginning in 2000, over 100 major sources of pollution in eight Illinois counties began trading pollution credits.

In 2003, "New York State proposed and attained commitments from nine "Northeast states to form a cap-and-trade "carbon dioxide emissions program for power generators, called the "Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI). This program launched on January 1, 2009 with the aim to reduce the carbon "budget" of each state's electricity generation sector to 10% below their 2009 allowances by 2018.[142]

Also in 2003, U.S. corporations were able to trade CO2 emission allowances on the "Chicago Climate Exchange under a voluntary scheme. In August 2007, the Exchange announced a mechanism to create "emission offsets for projects within the United States that cleanly destroy "ozone-depleting substances.[143]

Also in 2003, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) began to administer the NOx Budget Trading Program (NBP)under the NOx State Implementation Plan (also known as the "NOx SIP Call") The NOx Budget Trading Program was a market-based cap and trade program created to reduce emissions of nitrogen oxides (NOx) from power plants and other large combustion sources in the eastern United States. NOx is a prime ingredient in the formation of ground-level ozone (smog), a pervasive air pollution problem in many areas of the eastern United States. The NBP was designed to reduce NOx emissions during the warm summer months, referred to as the ozone season, when ground-level ozone concentrations are highest. In March 2008, EPA again strengthened the 8-hour ozone standard to 0.075 parts per million (ppm) from its previous 0.008 ppm.[144]

In 2006, the "California Legislature passed the California Global Warming Solutions Act, "AB-32, which was signed into law by Governor "Arnold Schwarzenegger. Thus far, flexible mechanisms in the form of project based offsets have been suggested for three main project types. The project types include: "manure management, forestry, and destruction of ozone-depleted substances. However, a recent ruling from Judge Ernest H. Goldsmith of San Francisco's Superior Court states that the rules governing California's cap-and-trade system were adopted without a proper analysis of alternative methods to reduce greenhouse gas emissions.[145] The tentative ruling, issued on January 24, 2011, argues that the "California Air Resources Board violated state environmental law by failing to consider such alternatives. If the decision is made final, the state would not be allowed to implement its proposed cap-and-trade system until the California Air Resources Board fully complies with the "California Environmental Quality Act.[146]

In February 2007, five U.S. states and four Canadian provinces joined together to create the "Western Climate Initiative (WCI), a regional greenhouse gas emissions trading system.[147] In July 2010, a meeting took place to further outline the cap-and-trade system.[148] In November 2011, Arizona, Montana, New Mexico, Oregon, Utah and Washington withdrew from the WCI.[149][150]

On November 17, 2008 President-elect "Barack Obama clarified, in a talk recorded for "YouTube, his intentions for the US to enter a cap-and-trade system to limit "global warming.[151]

SO2 emissions from Acid Rain Program sources have fallen from 17.3 million tons in 1980 to about 7.6 million tons in 2008, a decrease in emissions of 56 percent. Ozone season NOx emissions decreased by 43 percent between 2003 and 2008, even while energy demand remained essentially flat during the same period. CAIR will result in $85 billion to $100 billion in health benefits and nearly $2 billion in visibility benefits per year by 2015 and will substantially reduce premature mortality in the eastern United States.["citation needed] A recent EPA analysis shows that implementation of the Acid Rain Program is expected["by whom?] to reduce between 20,000 and 50,000 incidences of premature mortality annually due to reductions of ambient PM2.5 concentrations, and between 430 and 2,000 incidences annually due to reductions of ground-level ozone. NOx reductions due to the NOx Budget Trading Program have led to improvements in ozone and PM2.5, saving an estimated 580 to 1,800 lives in 2008.[152]

The "2010 United States federal budget proposes to support clean energy development with a 10-year investment of US $15 billion per year, generated from the sale of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions credits. Under the proposed cap-and-trade program, all GHG emissions credits would be auctioned off, generating an estimated $78.7 billion in additional revenue in FY 2012, steadily increasing to $83 billion by FY 2019.[153]

The "American Clean Energy and Security Act (H.R. 2454), a greenhouse gas cap-and-trade bill, was passed on June 26, 2009, in the House of Representatives by a vote of 219-212. The bill originated in the House Energy and Commerce Committee and was introduced by Representatives Henry A. Waxman and Edward J. Markey.[154] The political advocacy organizations "FreedomWorks and "Americans for Prosperity, funded by "brothers David and Charles Koch of "Koch Industries, encouraged the "Tea Party movement to focus on defeating the legislation.[155][156] Although cap and trade also gained a significant foothold in the Senate via the efforts of Republican "Lindsey Graham, Independent and former Democrat "Joe Lieberman, and Democrat "John Kerry,[157] the legislation died in the Senate.[158]

In 2012, under the auction, the reserve price, which is the price per ton of CO2 permit is $10. Some of the emitters obtain allowances for free, which is for the electric utilities, industrial facilities and natural gas distributors, whereas some of the others have to go to the auction.[159]

South Korea[edit]

South Korea's national emissions trading scheme officially launched on 1 January 2015, covering 525 entities from 23 sectors. With a three-year cap of 1.8687 billion tCO2e, it now forms the second largest carbon market in the world following the EU ETS.This amounts to roughly two thirds of the country's emissions. The Korean emissions trading scheme is part of the Republic of Korea's efforts to reduce greenhouse gas emissions by 30% compared to the business-as-usual scenario by 2020.[160]

China[edit]

In November 2011, China approved pilot tests of carbon trading in seven provinces and cities – Beijing, Chongqing, Shanghai, Shenzhen, Tianjin as well as Guangdong Province and Hubei Province, with different prices in each region.[161] The pilot is intended to test the waters and provide valuable lessons for the design of a national system in the near future. Their successes or failures will therefore have far reaching implications for carbon market development in China in terms of trust in a national carbon trading market. Some of the pilot regions can start trading as early as 2013/2014.[162] National trading is expected to start in 2017, latest in 2020. China currently emits about 30% of global emissions, and it became the largest emitter in the world. When the market launched, it will be the largest carbon market in the world.It has made a voluntary pledge under the UNFCCC to lower CO2 per unit of GDP by 40 to 45% in 2020 when comparing to the 2005 levels.[163]

India[edit]

Trading is set to begin in 2014 after a three-year rollout period. It is a mandatory energy efficiency trading scheme covering eight sectors responsible for 54 per cent of India’s industrial energy consumption. India has pledged a 20 to 25 per cent reduction in emissions intensity from 2005 levels by 2020. Under the scheme, annual efficiency targets will be allocated to firms. Tradable energy-saving permits will be issued depending on the amount of energy saved during a target year.[162]

Renewable energy certificates[edit]

Renewable Energy Certificates

"Renewable Energy Certificates (occasionally referred to as or "green tags" [citation required]), are a largely unrelated form of market-based instruments that are used to achieve renewable energy targets, which may be environmentally motivated (like emissions reduction targets), but may also be motivated by other aims, such as energy security or industrial policy.

Carbon market[edit]

Carbon emission trading

Carbon emissions trading is emissions trading specifically for "carbon dioxide (calculated in tonnes of "carbon dioxide equivalent or tCO2e) and currently makes up the bulk of emissions trading. It is one of the ways countries can meet their obligations under the "Kyoto Protocol to reduce carbon emissions and thereby "mitigate global warming.

personal carbon trading and "carbon offset

Market trend[edit]

Trading can be done directly between buyers and sellers, through several organised exchanges or through the many intermediaries active in the carbon market. The price of allowances is determined by supply and demand. As many as 40 million allowances have been traded per day. In 2012, 7.9 billion allowances were traded with a total value of €56 billion.[122] Carbon emissions trading declined in 2013, and is expected to decline in 2014.[164]

According to the "World Bank's Carbon Finance Unit, 374 million metric tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent (tCO2e) were exchanged through projects in 2005, a 240% increase relative to 2004 (110 mtCO2e)[165] which was itself a 41% increase relative to 2003 (78 mtCO2e).[166]

Global carbon markets have shrunk in value by 60% since 2011, but are expected to rise again in 2014.[167]

In terms of dollars, the World Bank has estimated that the size of the carbon market was 11 billion USD in 2005, 30 billion USD in 2006,[165] and 64 billion in 2007.[168]

The Marrakesh Accords of the Kyoto protocol defined the international trading mechanisms and registries needed to support trading between countries (sources can buy or sell allowances on the open market. Because the total number of allowances is limited by the cap, emission reductions are assured.).[169] Allowance trading now occurs between European countries and Asian countries. However, while the USA as a nation did not ratify the Protocol, many of its states are developing cap-and-trade systems and considering ways to link them together, nationally and internationally, to find the lowest costs and improve liquidity of the market.[170] However, these states also wish to preserve their individual integrity and unique features. For example, in contrast to other Kyoto-compliant systems, some states propose other types of greenhouse gas sources, different measurement methods, setting a maximum on the price of allowances, or restricting access to CDM projects. Creating instruments that are not "fungible (exchangeable) could introduce instability and make pricing difficult. Various proposals for linking these systems across markets are being investigated, and this is being coordinated by the "International Carbon Action Partnership (ICAP).[170][171]

Business reaction[edit]

In 2008, Barclays Capital predicted that the new carbon market would be worth $70 billion worldwide that year.[172] The voluntary offset market, by comparison, is projected to grow to about $4bn by 2010.[173]

23 "multinational corporations came together in the "G8 Climate Change Roundtable, a business group formed at the January 2005 "World Economic Forum. The group included "Ford, "Toyota, "British Airways, "BP and "Unilever. On June 9, 2005 the Group published a statement stating the need to act on climate change and stressing the importance of market-based solutions. It called on governments to establish "clear, transparent, and consistent price signals" through "creation of a long-term policy framework" that would include all major producers of greenhouse gases.[174] By December 2007, this had grown to encompass 150 global businesses.[175]

Business in the UK have come out strongly in support of emissions trading as a key tool to mitigate climate change, supported by NGOs.[176] However, not all businesses favor a trading approach. On December 11, 2008, "Rex Tillerson, the CEO of "Exxonmobil, said a "carbon tax is "a more direct, more transparent and more effective approach" than a cap-and-trade program, which he said, "inevitably introduces unnecessary cost and complexity". He also said that he hoped that the revenues from a carbon tax would be used to lower other taxes so as to be revenue neutral.[177]

The "International Air Transport Association, whose 230 member airlines comprise 93% of all international traffic, position is that trading should be based on "benchmarking", setting emissions levels based on industry averages, rather than ""grandfathering", which would use individual companies’ previous emissions levels to set their future permit allowances. They argue grandfathering "would penalise airlines that took early action to modernise their fleets, while a benchmarking approach, if designed properly, would reward more efficient operations".[178]

Measuring, reporting, verification[edit]

Assuring compliance with an emissions trading scheme requires measuring, reporting and verification (MRV).[179] Measurements are needed at each operator or installation. These measurements are reported to a regulator. For greenhouse gases, all trading countries maintain an inventory of emissions at national and installation level; in addition, trading groups within North America maintain inventories at the state level through "The Climate Registry. For trading between regions, these inventories must be consistent, with equivalent units and measurement techniques.[180]

In some industrial processes, emissions can be physically measured by inserting sensors and flowmeters in chimneys and stacks, but many types of activity rely on theoretical calculations instead of measurement. Depending on local legislation, measurements may require additional checks and verification by government or third party "auditors, prior or post submission to the local regulator.

Enforcement[edit]

In contrast to an ordinary market, in a pollution market the amount purchased is not necessarily the amount 'consumed' (= the amount of pollution emitted). A firm might buy a small amount of allowances but emit a much larger amount of pollution. This creates a troublesome "moral hazard problem.

This problem may be solved by a centralized regulator. The regulator should perform Measuring, Reporting and Verification (MRV) of the actual pollution levels, and "enforce the allowances.[181] Without effective MRV (Measuring, Enforcement methods include "fines and "sanctions for polluters that have exceeded their allowances. Concerns include the cost of MRV and enforcement, and the risk that facilities may lie about actual emissions. The net effect of a corrupt reporting system or poorly managed or financed regulator may be a discount on emission costs, and a hidden increase in actual emissions.

According to Nordhaus (2007, p. 27), strict enforcement of the Kyoto Protocol is likely to be observed in those countries and industries covered by the EU ETS.[182] Ellerman and Buchner (2007, p. 71) commented on the European Commission's (EC's) role in enforcing scarcity of permits within the EU ETS.[183] This was done by the EC's reviewing the total number of permits that member states proposed that their industries be allocated. Based on institutional and enforcement considerations, Kruger et al. (2007, pp. 130–131) suggested that emissions trading within developing countries might not be a realistic goal in the near-term.[184] Burniaux et al.. (2008, p. 56) argued that due to the difficulty in enforcing international rules against sovereign states, development of the carbon market would require negotiation and consensus-building.[185]

An alternative to centralized regulation is distributed regulation, in which the firms themselves are induced to inspect the other firms and report their misbehavior. It is possible to implement such systems in "subgame perfect equilibrium. Moore and Repullo[186] present an implementation with unbounded fines; Kahana and Mealem and Nitzan[187] present an implementation with bounded fines. Their work extends the work of Duggan and Roberts[188] by adding a second component which takes care of the moral hazard.

Criticism[edit]

""
""
Chicago Climate Justice activists protesting cap and trade legislation in front of "Chicago Climate Exchange building in Chicago Loop

Emissions trading has been criticised for a variety of reasons.

For example, in the popular science magazine "New Scientist, Lohmann (2006) argued that trading pollution allowances should be avoided as a climate stabilization policy for several reasons. First, climate change requires more radical changes than previous pollution trading schemes such as the US SO2 market. It requires reorganizing society and technology to "leave most remaining fossil fuels safely underground". Carbon trading schemes have tended to reward the heaviest polluters with 'windfall profits' when they are granted enough carbon credits to match historic production. Expensive long-term structural changes will not be made if there are cheaper sources of carbon credits which are often available from less developed countries, where they may be generated by local polluters at the expense of local communities.[189]

Research by Preston Teeter and Jorgen Sandberg has shown that the flexibility, and thus complexity, inherent in cap and trade schemes has resulted in a great deal of policy uncertainty surrounding these schemes. Such uncertainty has beset such schemes in Australia, Canada, China, the EU, India, Japan, New Zealand, and the US. As a result of this uncertainty, organizations have little incentive to innovate and comply, resulting in an ongoing battle of stakeholder contestation for the past two decades.[2]

Lohmann (2006b) supported conventional regulation, green taxes, and energy policies that are "justice-based" and "community-driven."[190] According to Carbon Trade Watch (2009), carbon trading has had a "disastrous track record." The effectiveness of the EU ETS was criticized, and it was argued that the CDM had routinely favoured "environmentally ineffective and socially unjust projects."[191]

"Annie Leonard's 2009 documentary The Story of Cap and Trade criticized carbon emissions trading for the free permits to major polluters giving them unjust advantages, cheating in connection with "carbon offsets, and as a distraction from the search for other solutions.[192]

Offsets[edit]

Forest campaigner Jutta Kill (2006) of European environmental group "FERN argued that offsets for emission reductions were not substitute for actual cuts in emissions. Kill stated that "[carbon] in trees is temporary: Trees can easily release carbon into the atmosphere through fire, disease, climatic changes, natural decay and timber harvesting."[193]

Permit supply level[edit]

Regulatory agencies run the risk of issuing too many emission credits, which can result in a very low price on emission permits (CCC, 2008, p. 140).[123] This reduces the incentive that permit-liable firms have to cut back their emissions. On the other hand, issuing too few permits can result in an excessively high permit price (Hepburn, 2006, p. 239).[194] This an argument for a hybrid instrument having a price-floor, i.e., a minimum permit price, and a price-ceiling, i.e., a limit on the permit price. However, a price-ceiling (safety value) removes the certainty of a particular quantity limit of emissions (Bashmakov et al.., 2001).[195]

Permit allocation versus auctioning[edit]

If polluters receive emission permits for free ("grandfathering"), this may be a reason for them not to cut their emissions because if they do they will receive fewer permits in the future (IMF, 2008, pp. 25–26).[196]

This "perverse incentive can be alleviated if permits are auctioned, i.e., sold to polluters, rather than giving them the permits for free (Hepburn, 2006, pp. 236–237).[194] Auctioning is a method for distributing emission allowances in a cap-and-trade system whereby allowances are sold to the highest bidder. Revenues from auctioning go to the government and can be used for development of sustainable technology[197] or to cut "distortionary taxes, thus improving the efficiency of the overall cap policy (Fisher et al.., 1996, p. 417).[198]

On the other hand, allocating permits can be used as a measure to protect domestic firms who are internationally exposed to competition (p. 237). This happens when domestic firms compete against other firms that are not subject to the same regulation. This argument in favor of allocation of permits has been used in the EU ETS, where industries that have been judged to be internationally exposed, e.g., cement and steel production, have been given permits for free (4CMR, 2008).[199]

This method of distribution may be combined with other forms of allowance distribution.[58]

Distributional effects[edit]

The US "Congressional Budget Office (CBO, 2009) examined the potential effects of the "American Clean Energy and Security Act on US households.[200] This act relies heavily on the free allocation of permits. The Bill was found to protect low-income consumers, but it was recommended that the Bill be made more efficient by reducing welfare provisions for corporations, and more resources be made available for consumer relief.

Linking[edit]

Distinct cap-and-trade systems can be linked together through the mutual or unilateral recognition of emissions allowances for compliance. Linking systems creates a larger carbon market, which can reduce overall compliance costs, increase market liquidity and generate a more stable carbon market.[201][202] Linking systems can also be politically symbolic as it shows willingness to undertake a common effort to reduce GHG emissions.[203] Some scholars have argued that linking may provide a starting point for developing a new, bottom-up international climate policy architecture, whereby multiple unique systems successively link their various systems.[204][205] In 2014, the U.S. state of California and the Canadian province of Québec successfully linked their systems. In 2015, the provinces of Ontario and Manitoba agreed to join the linked system between Quebec and California.[206]

The "International Carbon Action Partnership brings together regional, national and sub-national governments and public authorities from around the world to discuss important issues in the design of emissions trading schemes (ETS) and the way forward to a global carbon market. 30 national and subnational jurisdictions have joined ICAP as members since its establishment in 2007.[207]

See also[edit]

References[edit]

  1. ^ a b Stavins, Robert N. (November 2001). "Experience with Market-Based Environmental Policy Instruments" (PDF). Discussion Paper 01-58. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future. Retrieved 2010-05-20. Market-based instruments are regulations that encourage behavior through market signals rather than through explicit directives regarding pollution control levels or methods 
  2. ^ a b c Teeter, Preston; Sandberg, Jorgen (2016). "Constraining or Enabling Green Capability Development? How Policy Uncertainty Affects Organizational Responses to Flexible Environmental Regulations". British Journal of Management. "doi:10.1111/1467-8551.12188. 
  3. ^ "Tax Treaty Issues Related to Emissions Permits/Credits" (PDF). OECD. Retrieved 25 Oct 2014. 
  4. ^ "Climate Change 101: Understanding and Responding to Global Climate Change" (PDF). Cap and Trade. January 2011. 
  5. ^ "Allowance Trading". U.S Environment Protection Agency. Retrieved Oct 21, 2014. 
  6. ^ Judson Jaffe; Matthew Ranson; Robert N. Stavins (2009). "Linking Tradable Permit Systems: A Key Element of Emerging International Climate Policy Architecture" (PDF). Ecology Law Quarterly. 36 (789). Retrieved 2010-08-25. 
  7. ^ Tietenberg Tom (2003). "The Tradable-Permits Approach to Protecting the Commons: Lessons for Climate Change". Oxford Review of Economic Policy. 19 (3): 400–419. "doi:10.1093/oxrep/19.3.400. Retrieved 2010-08-25. 
  8. ^ Stavins, Robert N. (November 2001). "Experience with Market-Based Environmental Policy Instruments" (PDF). Discussion Paper 01-58. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future. Retrieved 2010-08-25. 
  9. ^ a b http://parlinfo.aph.gov.au/parlInfo/download/library/prspub/2501441/upload_binary/2501441.pdf;fileType=application/pdf
  10. ^ a b c d Montgomery, W.D (December 1972). "Markets in Licenses and Efficient Pollution Control Programs". Journal of Economic Theory. 5: 395–418. "doi:10.1016/0022-0531(72)90049-X. 
  11. ^ "Why Emission Trading is More Effective Than a Carbon Tax" (PDF). International Emissions Trading Association. 
  12. ^ EU Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) Archived December 14, 2009, at the "Wayback Machine.. UK Department of Energy and Climate Change. Retrieved 2009-01-19.
  13. ^ "USEPA's Clean Air Markets web site". US EPA. Retrieved 2009-11-03. 
  14. ^ a b Cap and Trade 101, "Center for American Progress, January 16, 2008.
  15. ^ (Boswall, J. and Lee, R. (2002). Economics, ethics and the environment. London: Cavendish 66.)
  16. ^ "Cap and Trade 101". United States Environmental Protection Agency. EPA. Retrieved 27 October 2014. 
  17. ^ Sullivan, Arthur, and Steven M. Sheffrin. Economics: Principles in action. Upper Saddle River, New Jersey, 2003. "ISBN 0-13-063085-3
  18. ^ "How can and trade works". Environmental Defense Fund. 2014 Environmental Defense Fund. Retrieved 27 October 2014. 
  19. ^ "Archived copy" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2014-09-29. Retrieved 2014-11-10. 
  20. ^ "Key points: Update Paper 6: Carbon pricing and reducing Australia's emissions". Garnaut Climate Change Review. 17 March 2011. Retrieved 16 July 2013. 
  21. ^ a b Stavins, Robert N (1998). "What Can We Learn from the Grand Policy Experiment? Lessons from SO2 Allowance Trading". The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 3. American Economic Association. 12 (3): 69–88. "doi:10.1257/jep.12.3.69. "JSTOR 2647033. 
  22. ^ Bryner, Gary C. Blue Skies, Green Politics: the Clean Air Act of 1990. Washington, D.C.:Congressional Quarterly Inc., 1951.
  23. ^ (Hall, JV and Walton, AL, ‘A case study in pollution markets: dismal science US. Dismal reality’ (1996) XIV Contemporary Economic Policy 67.)
  24. ^ (Boswall, J. and Lee, R. (2002). Economics, ethics and the environment. London: Cavendish 65.)
  25. ^ "Tax Treaty Issues Related to Emissions Permits/Credits" (PDF). OECD. OECD. Retrieved Nov 22, 2014. 
  26. ^ Lavelle, Marianne (November 3, 2010). "A U.S. Cap-And-Trade Experiment to End". National Geographic. Retrieved November 7, 2010. 
  27. ^ "CantorCO2e Launches First Internet CER Auction" (Press release). CantorCO2e. 2008-09-09. Retrieved 2010-01-27. 
  28. ^ "Carbon Place . EU - Market with carbon credits - EUA, CER, ERU, VER, AAU-S, AAU-G". Retrieved 25 September 2015. 
  29. ^ Kanter, James (2007-06-20). "Carbon trading: Where greed is green". The New York Times. Retrieved 2010-01-27. 
  30. ^ (Carbon dioxide, methane, nitrous oxide, hydroflurocarbons, perfluorocarbons and sulphur hexafluoride.)
  31. ^ (Boswall, J. and Lee, R. (2002). Economics, ethics and the environment. London: Cavendish 62.)
  32. ^ Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour (1967) An Economic Analysis of the Control of Sulphur Oxides Air Pollution DHEW Program Analysis Report No. 1967-69 Washington, D.C.: Ernst and Ernst.
  33. ^ Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1968). A Cost-Effectiveness Study of Particulate and SOx Emission Control in the New York Metropolitan Area. NTIS: PB-227 121/1. Contract Number: PH-86-68-37. Washington, D.C.: Ernst and Ernst.
  34. ^ Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1969). A Cost-Effectiveness Study of Air Pollution Abatement in the Greater Kansas City Area. NTIS: PB-227 116/1. Washington, D.C.: Ernst and Ernst.
  35. ^ Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1969). A Cost-effectiveness Study of Air Pollution Abatement in the National Capital Area. NAPCA Contract No. PH 86-68-37, NTIS: PB227110. Washington, D.C.: Ernst and Ernst.
  36. ^ Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1970). Applications of Cost-Effectiveness Analysis to Air Pollution Control. DHEW Contract No. CPA 22-69-17. Washington, D.C.: Ernst and Ernst.
  37. ^ Burton, E. S., and William Sanjour (1970) A Simulation Approach to Air Pollution Abatement Program Planning. Socio-Economic Planning Science 4: 147–150.
  38. ^ Burton, Ellison S., Edward H. Pechan III, and William Sanjour. (1973). A Survey of Air Pollution Control Models. Rolf A. Deininger, ed. Ann Arbor: Ann Arbor Science Publishers.
  39. ^ Burton, Ellison S., Edward H. Pechan III, and William Sanjour. (1973). Solving the Air Pollution Control Puzzle. Environmental Science and Technology 7: 412.
  40. ^ U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. (1972). The Economics of Clean Air, Annual Report of the Environmental Protection Agency to the Congress of the United States. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
  41. ^ Voss, Jan-Peter. (2007). Innovation processes in governance: the development of emissions trading as a new policy instrument. Science and Public Policy 34: 329–343.
  42. ^ Coase, Ronald H. (1960). ""The Problem of Social Cost". "Journal of Law and Economics. 3 (1): 1–44. "doi:10.1086/466560. 
  43. ^ Crocker, T. D. (1966). The Structuring of Atmospheric Pollution Control Systems. The Economics of Air Pollution. H. Wolozin. New York, W. W. Norton & Co.: 61–86.
  44. ^ Dales, John H. 1968. Land, Water, and Ownership. The Canadian Journal of Economics 1(4) 791–804.
  45. ^ Gillenwater, Michael; Seres, Stephen (March 2011). "The Clean Development Mechanism: A Review of the First International Offset Program" (PDF). Pew Center on Global Climate Change. p. 6.  Available via Center for Climate and Energy Solutions, www.c2es.org. Retrieved 2016-11-26.
  46. ^ Coniff, Richard (Aug. 2009). "The Political History of Cap and Trade". Smithsonian Magazine. Retrieved 1-13-2011
  47. ^ (Grimeaud, D, ‘An overview of the policy and legal aspects of the international climate change regime’ (2001) 9(2) Environmental Liability 39.)
  48. ^ (Stewart, R, ‘Economic incentives for environmental protection: opportunities and obstacles’, in Revesz, R, Sands, P and Stewart, R (eds), Environment Law, the Economy and Sustainable Development, 2000, Cambridge: CUP.)
  49. ^ (create shortcut for Kyoto Protocol)(Boswall, J. and Lee, R. (2002). Economics, ethics and the environment. London: Cavendish 63.)
  50. ^ a b Roos, Joseph A.; Barber, Valerie; Brackley, Allen M. (March 2011). Cap and Trade: Offsets and Implications for Alaska (PDF) http://www.arlis.org/docs/vol1/C/713310520.pdf. Retrieved 27 October 2014.  Missing or empty |title= ("help)
  51. ^ "China's national carbon market to start in 2016 -official". Reuters UK. Retrieved 25 September 2015. 
  52. ^ Diesendorf, Mark (July 14, 2014). Sustainable Energy Solutions for Climate Change. Routledge. 
  53. ^ "Majority of Poll Respondents Say U.S. Should Limit Greenhouse Gases", Washington Post
  54. ^ "Poll Position: New Zogby Poll Shows 71% Support for Waxman-Markey", Wall Street Journal
  55. ^ "Poll: Americans Support Strong Climate, Energy Policies",Yale Climate & Energy Institute
  56. ^ a b Roberts, David (26 Jun 2009). "What can we learn from polls on cap-and-trade?". grist. Retrieved 27 October 2014. 
  57. ^ "IBD editorial board claims that cap-and-trade is unpopular in America", PolitiFact
  58. ^ a b c Center for Climate and Energy Solutions (January 2011). "CAP AND TRADE KEY TERMS GLOSSARY" (PDF). CLIMATE CHANGE 101: CAP AND TRADE. Retrieved 27 October 2014. 
  59. ^ Chomitz, Kenneth M (1999). Policy Research Working Paper Series. 2357. The World Bank. "SSRN 630729Freely accessible.  Missing or empty |title= ("help); |contribution= ignored ("help)
  60. ^ a b c Rosen and Gayer, Harvey S. and Ted (2008). Public Finance. New York: McGraw-Hill Irwin. pp. 90–94. "ISBN "978-0-07-351128-3. 
  61. ^ Center for Climate and Energy Solutions (January 2011). "CAP AND TRADE KEY TERMS GLOSSARY" (PDF). Climate Change 101: Cap and Trade: 11. 
  62. ^ a b Burney, Nelson E. (2010). Carbon Tax and Cap-and-trade Tools : Market-based Approaches for Controlling Greenhouse Gases. New York: Nova Science Publishers, Inc. "ISBN "9781608761371. 
  63. ^ Durning, Alan (July 2009). "carBon tax vS. cap and trade" (PDF). Cap and Trade 101 A Federal Climate Policy Primer: 28. Retrieved 27 October 2014. 
  64. ^ http://www.ucl.ac.uk/opticon1826/archive/issue9/researchnotes/S_H_Calel.pdf
  65. ^ Yujie Lu; Xinyuan Zhu; Qingbin Cui (2012). "Effectiveness and equity implications of carbon policies in the United States construction industry". Building and Environment. Elsevier Ltd. 49: 259–269. "doi:10.1016/j.buildenv.2011.10.002. 
  66. ^ Ramseur, Jonathan L. (April 16, 2010), "Estimating Offset Supply in a Cap-and-Trade Program" (PDF), "Congressional Research Service: 1, retrieved February 15, 2011 
  67. ^ Map: Pollution hotspots, BBC map of areas that suffer from intense local pollution, BBC News, 2004-12-13. Retrieved 2009-10-19.
  68. ^ "Chicago Climate Exchange prices". Chicagoclimatex.com. 2009-08-04. Retrieved 2009-11-03. 
  69. ^ Weitzman, M. L. (1974-10). "Prices vs. Quantities". The Review of Economic Studies. The Review of Economic Studies Ltd. 41 (4): 477–491. "doi:10.2307/2296698. "JSTOR 2296698.  Check date values in: |date= ("help)
  70. ^ Philibert, Cédric (October 2006). "Certainty versus ambition economic efficiency in mitigating climate change" (PDF). International Energy Agency Working Paper Series. Paris: International Energy Agency/OECD. LTO/2006/03. Retrieved 2010-01-24. 
  71. ^ Jacoby, D.H.; Ellerman, A.D. (March 2004). "The safety valve and climate policy". Energy Policy. 32 (4): 481–49. "doi:10.1016/S0301-4215(03)00150-2. Retrieved 2009-11-03. 
  72. ^ a b c World Bank (2010). "World Development Report 2010: Development and Climate Change" (PDF). The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, D.C. 20433. Retrieved 2010-04-06. 
  73. ^ Barker, T.; et al. (2007). "11.7.2 Carbon leakage.". In B. Metz; et al. Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective. Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. Retrieved 2010-04-05. 
  74. ^ Goldemberg, J.; et al. (1996). J.P. Bruce; et al., eds. Introduction: scope of the assessment. (PDF). Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. This version: Printed by Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. PDF version: IPCC website. "doi:10.2277/0521568544. "ISBN "978-0-521-56854-8. 
  75. ^ Barker, T.; et al. (2007). "Executive Summary. In (book chapter): Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective. In (book): Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz et al. Eds.)". Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. Retrieved 2010-04-05. 
  76. ^ Houser, Trevor; Rob Bradley; Britt Childs Staley; Jake Werksman; Robert Heilmayr (2008). Leveling The Carbon Playing Field: International Competition and U.S. Climate Policy Design. Peterson Institute for International Economics. 
  77. ^ "Kyoto Protocol". UNFCCC website. Retrieved 2009-09-16. 
  78. ^ "Climate Change 2007: Mitigation of Climate Change, Summary for Policymakers from IPCC Fourth Assessment Report" (PDF). Working Group III, "IPCC. 2007-05-04. pp. Item 25, page 33. Retrieved 2007-05-10. ["dead link]
  79. ^ Robert W., Hahn (November 2011). "The effect of Allowance Allocations on Cap-and-Trade System Performance" (PDF). Journal of Law and Econimics. 54 (4). Retrieved November 22, 2014. 
  80. ^ IPCC (2007). "Glossary J-P. In (book section): Annex I. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz et al. Eds.)". Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. Retrieved 2010-04-23. 
  81. ^ "LULUCF under the Kyoto Protocol". UNFCCC website. Retrieved 2010-04-28. 
  82. ^ "UNFCCC Countries 1990 to 2012 emissions targets". UNFCCC website. 2008-05-14. Retrieved 2009-11-03. 
  83. ^ "Emissions Trading". UNFCCC website. Retrieved 2009-09-16. 
  84. ^ (Yamin, F, Burniaux, J-M ad Nentjes, A, ‘Kyoto Mechanisms: key issues for policy makers for CoP-6; international environmental agreements (2001) 1 Politics, Law and Economics 187-218.),
  85. ^ (Haites, E and Yamin, F, ‘The clean development mechanism:proposals for its operation and governance’ (2000) 10 Global Environmental Change 27-45.)
  86. ^ (Boswall, J. and Lee, R. (2002). Economics, ethics and the environment. London: Cavendish 63-64.)
  87. ^ Carbon Trust (March 2009). "Global Carbon Mechanisms: Emerging lessons and implications (CTC748)". Carbon Trust website. Retrieved 2010-03-31. 
  88. ^ "The Greenhouse Gas Reduction Scheme". NSW: Greenhouse Gas Reduction Scheme Administrator. 2010-01-04. Retrieved 2010-01-16. 
  89. ^ Passey, Rob; MacGill, Iain; Outhred, Hugh (2007). CEEM discussion paper DP_070822. Sydney: The UNSW Centre for Energy and Environmental Markets (CEEM). Retrieved 2009-11-03.  Missing or empty |title= ("help); |contribution= ignored ("help)
  90. ^ "Abbott defends carbon tax interview". ABC News. Retrieved 25 September 2015. 
  91. ^ [1]
  92. ^ Leslie, Tim (2011-02-24). "Gillard unveils Carbon Price Details". ABC News. 
  93. ^ Hudson, Phillip (2011-02-26). "Tony Abbott calls for election on carbon tax". Herald Sun. Retrieved 2011-05-05. 
  94. ^ Johnston, Matt (October 12, 2011). "Carbon tax bills pass lower house of federal Parliament". Herald Sun. Retrieved October 12, 2011. 
  95. ^ AAP with Reuters (2011-11-08). "Carbon tax gets green light in Senate". Sydney Morning Herald. 
  96. ^ "Opposition vows to repeal carbon tax". Sydney Morning Herald. 2011-10-02. 
  97. ^ http://indymedia.org.au/2013/09/20/abbott-governments-first-actions-trash-climate-change-education-carbon-pricing Accessed 8/11/2013
  98. ^ "Carbon tax scrapped: PM Tony Abbott sees key election promise fulfilled after Senate votes for repeal". ABC News. Retrieved 25 September 2015. 
  99. ^ "Parker, David (10 September 2008). "Historic climate change legislation passes". New Zealand Government Media Release. Retrieved 10 September 2008. 
  100. ^ "Climate Change Response (Emissions Trading) Amendment Act 2008 No 85". www.legislation.govt.nz. Parliamentary Counsel Office. 25 September 2008. Retrieved 25 January 2010. 
  101. ^ "Hon Nick Smith (25 November 2009). "Balanced new law important step on climate change". New Zealand Government Press Release. Retrieved 14 June 2010. 
  102. ^ "ETS Amendment Bill passes third reading" (Press release). New Zealand Government. 9 November 2012. Retrieved 12 November 2012. 
  103. ^ MfE (October 2012). "New Zealand's Greenhouse Gas Inventory 1990–2010 and Net Position Snapshot". Ministry for the Environment. Retrieved 10 November 2012. 
  104. ^ a b c MfE (September 2009). "Summary of the proposed changes to the NZ ETS". Emissions trading bulletin No 11. Ministry for the Environment, NZ Government. Retrieved 15 May 2010. 
  105. ^ MfE (April 2010). "New Zealand's Greenhouse Gas Inventory 1990–2008". ME 1009. Ministry for the Environment. "ISSN 1179-223X. Retrieved 22 May 2010. 
  106. ^ a b MfE (14 January 2010). "How will the changes impact on forestry?". Questions and answers about amendments to the New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS). Ministry for the Environment, NZ Government (www.climatechange.govt.nz). Retrieved 16 May 2010. 
  107. ^ "Waste - New Zealand Climate change information". Ministry for the Environment. 15 July 2011. Retrieved 26 July 2011. 
  108. ^ "Emissions Trading Worldwide ICAP Status Report 2015" (PDF). ICAP. 10 February 2015. Retrieved 16 March 2015. 
  109. ^ "New Zealand Units (NZUs)". Climate change information New Zealand. Ministry for the Environment, NZ Government (www.climatechange.govt.nz). 18 June 2010. Retrieved 13 August 2010. In the short term, the Government is unlikely to sell emission units because the Kyoto units allocated to New Zealand will be needed to support New Zealand's international obligations, as well as allocation to eligible sectors under the emissions trading scheme. 
  110. ^ "Who will get a free allocation of emission units?". Questions and answers about the emissions trading scheme. Ministry for the Environment, NZ Government. 14 January 2010. Retrieved 15 May 2010. 
  111. ^ MfE (September 2009). "Agriculture". Summary of the proposed changes to the NZ ETS - Emissions Trading Bulletin 11. Ministry for the Environment, NZ Government. Retrieved 16 May 2010. 
  112. ^ MfE (September 2009). "Industrial allocation update". Emissions trading bulletin No 12, INFO 441. Ministry for the Environment, NZ Government. Retrieved 8 August 2010. The Bill changes the allocation provisions of the existing CCRA from allocating a fixed pool of emissions to an uncapped approach to allocation. There is no longer an explicit limit on the number of New Zealand units (NZUs) that can be allocated to the industrial sector. 
  113. ^ MfE (14 January 2010). "How will free allocation of emission units to the industrial sector work now?". Questions and answers about amendments to the New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS). Ministry for the Environment, NZ Government. Retrieved 16 May 2010. 
  114. ^ Bertram, Geoff; Terry, Simon (2010). The Carbon Challenge: New Zealand’s Emissions Trading Scheme. Bridget Williams Books, Wellington. "ISBN "978-1-877242-46-5. The New Zealand ETS does not fit this model because there is no cap and therefore no certainty as to the volume of emissions with which the national economy must operate 
  115. ^ "New bill 'weakens ETS' says Environment Commissioner" (Press release). Parliamentary Commissioner for the Environment. 15 October 2009. Retrieved 15 October 2009. The allocation of free carbon credits to industrial processes is extremely generous and removes the carbon price signal where New Zealand needs one the most 
  116. ^ "Revised ETS an insult to New Zealanders" (Press release). Greenpeace New Zealand. 14 September 2009. Retrieved 12 October 2009. We now have on the table a pathetic ETS which won’t actually do anything to reduce emissions 
  117. ^ "Issues statement for public consultation". NZ ETS Review 2011. Ministry for the Environment. 21 April 2011. Retrieved 4 November 2011. 
  118. ^ Jones, B.; et al. (October 2007). "Chapter 1. Global Prospects and Policy Issues". World Economic and Financial Surveys, World Economic Outlook, Globalization and Inequality. IMF. Retrieved 2010-04-26.  |contribution= ignored ("help)
  119. ^ Climate Change: The European Union's Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) Archived August 30, 2006, at the "Wayback Machine.
  120. ^ "Britain, California to join forces on global warming". The Washington Times. 2006-07-31. Retrieved 2009-11-03. 
  121. ^ Wagner, M.: Firms, the Framework Convention on Climate Change & the EU Emissions Trading System. Corporate Energy Management Strategies to Address Climate Change and GHG Emissions in the European Union. Lüneburg: Centre for Sustainability Management 2004, p.12 [2]["permanent dead link] CSM Lüneburg
  122. ^ a b http://ec.europa.eu/clima/publications/docs/factsheet_ets_en.pdf
  123. ^ a b CCC (December 2008). "Chapter 4: Carbon markets and carbon prices. In: Building a low-carbon economy – The UK's contribution to tackling climate change. The First Report of the Committee on Climate Change. December 2008". Print version: The Stationery Office. This version: CCC website. Retrieved 2010-04-26.  External link in |publisher= ("help)
  124. ^ Grubb, M.; et al. (3 August 2009). "Climate Policy and Industrial Competitiveness: Ten Insights from Europe on the EU Emissions Trading System". Climate Strategies. Retrieved 2010-04-14. 
  125. ^ Kanen, J.L.M. "Carbon Trading & Prcing". book Fulton Publishing, publication (December 2006) 68:69
  126. ^ IEA (2007). "European Commission Environment - EU action against climate change" (PDF). European Commission Environment. p. 24. Retrieved 2010-08-01. 
  127. ^ Norwegian Ministry of the Environment (2007). "The Norwegian Government accepts to include the EU Emissions Trading Directive in the EEA agreement". European Commission Environment. p. 24. Retrieved 2010-08-03. 
  128. ^ Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (2010). "Economic Survey of Norway 2010: Sustainable development: climate change and fisheries policiesEconomic Survey of Norway 2010: Sustainable development: climate change and fisheries policies". Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development. pp. n/a. Retrieved 2010-08-03. ["dead link]
  129. ^ "EU greenhouse gas emissions and targets". European Commission. Retrieved Oct 23, 2014. 
  130. ^ "Tokyo Metropolitan Government Leads Japan, Launches Own GHG Emissions Cap-and-Trade Program". Artcraft Japan For your Japanese Heart and Soul. 2010-07-16. Retrieved 2010-08-05. 
  131. ^ "Tokyo Metropolitan Government Leads Japan, Launches Own GHG Emissions Cap-and-Trade Program". Artcraft Japan For your Japanese Heart and Soul. July 16, 2010. 
  132. ^ a b http://www.sei-international.org/mediamanager/documents/Publications/china-cluster/SEI-FORES-2012-China-Carbon-Emissions.pdf
  133. ^ "Tokyo emissions trading plan may become a model for others". World Council for Sustainable Development. 2010-02-111. Retrieved 2010-08-12.  Check date values in: |date= ("help)
  134. ^ a b Business Green (2010-04-08). "Tokyo kicks off carbon trading scheme". The Guardian. Retrieved 2010-12-29. 
  135. ^ "Urban Environment and Climate Change - Publications". Retrieved 25 September 2015. 
  136. ^ "Emissions Trading Worldwide ICAP Status Report 2015" (PDF). 
  137. ^ "Acid Rain Program 2007 Progress Report". Clean Air Markets - Air & Radiation. US EPA. January 2009. Retrieved 2011-07-25. 
  138. ^ Carlson, Curtis, Dallas Burtraw, Maureen Cropper, and Karen L. Palmer. 2000. "Sulfur dioxide control by electric utilities: What are the gains from trade?" Journal of Political Economy 108: 1292-1326.
  139. ^ "Cross-State Air Pollution Rule (CSAPR)". United States Environment Protection Agency. 2011-07-09. Retrieved 2011-07-10. 
  140. ^ [3], Center for Climate and Energy Solutions, January, 2014
  141. ^ "Emissions Reduction Market System What Is ERMS?". Illinois EPA. 2007. 
  142. ^ Memorandum of Understanding - Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative
  143. ^ Brüning, Kristian; Cohen, Jeff (2008-03-07). "Beyond the Kyoto six". Carbon Finance. Fulton Publishing Ltd. Archived from the original on 2011-07-27. Retrieved 2011-07-26. 
  144. ^ [4], Environmental Protection Agency, August 13, 2010
  145. ^ Barringer, Felicity (4 February 2011). "California Law to Curb Greenhouse Gases Faces a Legal Hurdle". The New York Times. Retrieved 9 February 2011. 
  146. ^ Buchanan, Wyatt (4 February 2011). "Calif. cap-trade plan dealt blow by S.F. judge". San Francisco Chronicle. Retrieved 9 February 2011. 
  147. ^ [5] Western Climate Initiative
  148. ^ California, New Mexico and 3 Canadian provinces outline regional cap-and-trade program, Los Angeles Times, July 28, 2010
  149. ^ "Six US states leave the Western Climate Initiative" (November 18, 2011). S&P Global Platts. www.platts.com. Retrieved 2016-11-26.
  150. ^ "6 States Pull Out of Western Climate Initiative" (November 22, 2011). SustainableBusiness.com News. Retrieved 2016-11-26.
  151. ^ Barack Obama (2008-11-17). "A New Chapter on Climate Change". YouTube. Retrieved 2009-04-03. 
  152. ^ "Cap and Trade". United States Environmental Protection Agency. EPA. Retrieved 27 October 2014. 
  153. ^ "President's Budget Draws Clean Energy Funds from Climate Measure". Renewable Energy World. Retrieved 2009-04-03. 
  154. ^ "The American Clean Energy and Security Act (H.R. 2454)". Energycommerce.house.gov. 2009-06-01. Retrieved 2010-06-14. 
  155. ^ "Dryzek, John S.; "Norgaard, Richard B.; Schlosberg, David (2011). The Oxford Handbook of Climate Change and Society. Oxford University Press. p. 154. "ISBN "9780199683420. 
  156. ^ "Mayer, Jane (August 30, 2010). "Covert Operations: The billionaire brothers who are waging a war against Obama". "The New Yorker. Retrieved March 20, 2015. 
  157. ^ Ryan Lizza (10/11/2010). "As the World Burns: How the Senate and the White House missed their best chance to deal with climate change". The New Yorker.  Check date values in: |date= ("help)
  158. ^ Turin, Dustin R. (2012). "The Challenges of Climate Change Policy: Explaining the Failure of Cap and Trade in the United States With a Multiple-Streams Framework". Student Pulse. 4 (6). 
  159. ^ [6], Center for Climate and Energy Solutions
  160. ^ "Emissions Trading Worldwide ICAP Status Report 2015" (PDF). 
  161. ^ Andrews-Speed, Philip (November 2014). "China's Energy Policymaking Processes and Their Consequences". The National Bureau of Asian Research Energy Security Report. Retrieved December 24, 2014. 
  162. ^ a b "Factbox: Carbon trading schemes around the world". Reuters. Retrieved 25 September 2015. 
  163. ^ "China could launch national carbon market in 2016". CLIMATE HOME. 
  164. ^ "Global carbon market to rise 15% in value in 2014". Climate Home. Retrieved 25 September 2015. 
  165. ^ a b "Carbon Finance" (PDF). Carbon Finance. 2009-01-15. Retrieved 2009-04-03. 
  166. ^ "Microsoft Word — Carbon Market Study 2005 - FINAL — Letter.doc" (PDF). Carbonfinance.org. 2009-01-15. Retrieved 2009-04-03. 
  167. ^ "Global carbon markets have shrunk in value by 60% since 2011". REDD-Monitor. Retrieved 25 September 2015. 
  168. ^ "Carbon Finance" (PDF). Carbon Finance. 2009-01-15. Retrieved 2009-04-03. 
  169. ^ "Allowance Trading Basic". US Environmental Protection Agency. Retrieved 26 Oct 2014. 
  170. ^ a b Stavins, Robert N.; Jaffe, Judson (2008). Linkage of Tradable Permit Systems in International Climate Policy Architecture. Harvard Project on International Climate Agreements. 
  171. ^ International Carbon Action Partnership ICAP website
  172. ^ Turney, Drew. "The Cap and Trade Pollution Solution". Net Resources International,. Retrieved 21 May 2012. 
  173. ^ The carbon market Fiona Harvey, FT April 27, 2007
  174. ^ "Archived copy" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2013-05-08. Retrieved 2013-03-23. 
  175. ^ List of climate leaders EPA December 12
  176. ^ "Meeting the Energy Challenge A White Paper on Energy May 2007" (PDF). UK Department of Trade and Industry. Retrieved 2009-11-03.  |contribution= ignored ("help)
  177. ^ "Exxon supports carbon tax". Calgary Herald News. 2009-01-09. 
  178. ^ "What You Need to Know About Emissions Trading" (PDF). International Air Transport Association. Archived from the original (PDF) on March 3, 2007. Retrieved 2009-09-26. 
  179. ^ "MRV&Enforcement". International Carbon Action Partnership. International Carbon Action Partnership (ICAP). Retrieved 26 Oct 2014. 
  180. ^ Tiwari, Gopal Nath; Agrawal, Basant (2010). Building integrated photovoltaic thermal systems : for sustainable developments. Cambridge: Royal Society of Chemistry. "ISBN "1-84973-090-3. 
  181. ^ Ott, Hermann E. (1998-10-26). "Emissions Trading in the Kyoto Protocol, Finished and Unfinished Business". Linkages Journal. 4. 3. 
  182. ^ Nordhaus, W.D. (2007). "To Tax of Not to Tax: Alternative Approaches to Slowing Global Warming" (PDF). Review of Environmental Economics and Policy. 1 (1). Retrieved 2010-04-28. 
  183. ^ Ellerman, A.D.; B.K. Buchner (2007). "The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins, Allocation, and Early Results" (PDF). Review of Environmental Economics and Policy. 1 (1). Retrieved 2010-04-28. 
  184. ^ Kruger, J.; et al. (2007). "Decentralization in the EU Emissions Trading Scheme and Lessons for Global Policy" (PDF). Review of Environmental Economics and Policy. 1 (1). Retrieved 2010-04-28. 
  185. ^ Burniaux, J-M.; et al. (6 June 2009). The Economics of Climate Change Mitigation: How to Build the Necessary Global Action in a Cost-Effective Manner. Economics Department Working Papers No. 701. OECD website. Retrieved 2010-04-24. 
  186. ^ Moore, John; Repullo, Rafael (1988). "Subgame Perfect Implementation". Econometrica. 56 (5): 1191. "doi:10.2307/1911364. "JSTOR 1911364. 
  187. ^ Kahana, Nava; Mealem, Yosef; Nitzan, Shmuel (2008). "A complete implementation of the efficient allocation of pollution". Economics Letters. 101 (2): 142. "doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2008.07.003. 
  188. ^ Duggan, John; Roberts, Joanne (2002). "Implementing the Efficient Allocation of Pollution". American Economic Review. 92 (4): 1070. "doi:10.1257/00028280260344614. 
  189. ^ Lohmann, Larry (2006-12-05). "A licence to carry on polluting?". New Scientist. 2580. Archived from the original on 2006-12-05. Retrieved 2010-07-17. 
  190. ^ Lohmann, Larry (2006b). "Ways forward (The Corner House)". The Corner House. Retrieved 2009-04-03. 
  191. ^ Carbon Trade Watch (November 2009). "Carbon Trading – How it works and why it fails". Dag Hammarskjöld Foundation. Retrieved 2010-08-04. 
  192. ^ Annie Leonard (2009). "The Story of Cap and Trade". The Story of Stuff Project. Retrieved 2010-10-31. 
  193. ^ Kill, J. (July 2006). "10 things you should know about tree 'offsets'". "New Internationalist. Retrieved 2010-04-28. 
  194. ^ a b Hepburn, C. (2006). "Regulating by prices, quantities or both: an update and an overview" (PDF). Oxford Review of Economic Policy. 22 (2): 226–247. "doi:10.1093/oxrep/grj014. Retrieved August 30, 2009. 
  195. ^ Bashmakov, I.; et al. (2001). "6.2.2.3 Tradable Permits.". In B. Metz; et al. 6. Policies, Measures, and Instruments. Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: GRID-Arendal website. Retrieved 2010-04-26.  External link in |publisher= ("help)
  196. ^ IMF (March 2008). "Fiscal Implications of Climate Change" (PDF). International Monetary Fund, Fiscal Affairs Department. Retrieved 2010-04-26. 
  197. ^ "Climate change; The greening of America". The Economist. 2007-01-25. Retrieved 2009-04-03. 
  198. ^ Fisher, B.S.; et al. (1996). "An Economic Assessment of Policy Instruments for Combating Climate Change". In J.P. Bruce; et al. Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (PDF). Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. PDF version: IPCC website. "doi:10.2277/0521568544. "ISBN "978-0-521-56854-8. 
  199. ^ 4CMR (19 June 2008). "Memorandum by the Cambridge Centre for Climate Change Mitigation Research. European Union – Minutes of Evidence, Wednesday 8 October 2008. European Union Committee, Session 2007-2008, Thirty-third Report: The Revision of the EU's Emissions Trading System". UK Parliament website. Retrieved 2010-04-28. 
  200. ^ Stone, Chad; Shaw, Hannah (2009-07-10). "Senate can strengthen climate legislation by reducing corporate welfare and boosting true consumer relief" (PDF). Centre for Budget and Policy Priorities. Retrieved 2010-01-27. 
  201. ^ https://icapcarbonaction.com/index.php?option=com_attach&task=download&id=241
  202. ^ Burtraw, D., Palmer, K. L., Munnings, C., Weber, P., & Woerman, M., 2013: Linking by Degrees: Incremental Alignment of Cap-and-Trade Markets. SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.2249955
  203. ^ Flachsland, C., Marschinski, R., & Edenhofer, O., 2009: To link or not to link: benefits and disadvantages of linking cap-and-trade systems. Climate Policy, 9(4), 358–372. doi:10.3763/cpol.2009.0626
  204. ^ Ranson, M., & Stavins, R., 2013: Linkage of Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trading Systems - Learning from Experience. Discussion Paper Resources For The Future, No. 42
  205. ^ The House of Commons Energy and Climate Committee, 2015: Linking emissions trading systems. London.
  206. ^ http://www.cbc.ca/news/canada/montreal/quebec-ontario-manitoba-cap-and-trade-1.3354002. CBC news Posted: Dec 07, 2015. "Quebec, Ontario, Manitoba sign agreement to link cap-and-trade systems."
  207. ^ "International Carbon Action Partnership (ICAP)". International Carbon Action Partnership. Retrieved 25 September 2015. 

Further reading[edit]

External links[edit]

) )